Subject: What the split might be
From: npersily@law.upenn.edu
Date: 12/11/2003, 3:07 PM
To: "Lowenstein, Daniel" <lowenstein@LAW.UCLA.EDU>
CC: "Election-law Listserver (election-law@majordomo.lls.edu)" <election-law@majordomo.lls.edu>

In response to Dan's points:

I think Scalia was right about the Harvard faculty quote. I seem to 
remember it as from Buckley (that is, William F., not v. Valeo) also.

As for the split, I do not think Justice Souter is a guaranteed vote 
for the Appellants. He was not terribly active in the questioning, 
except to suggest that partisan gerrymanders are successful.  Ginsburg 
was relatively silent, so I don't really know where she will come 
out.  Stevens is the only sure vote for the Appellants, and I suspect 
from past patterns Ginsburg might join him.  I would have thought 
Breyer was not guaranteed, but his dissent from denial of cert in the 
Michigan case a year earlier plus his comments at oral argument make 
him seem like a vote for the Appellants.  It could be the typical 5-4 
split, but I think there might be some strange concurrences from the 
more "liberal" Justices.

And Dan, how could anyone regret having you at a symposium? Without 
your shoulders to stand on, we junior election law types would be 
suspended in mid-air. 


Quoting "Lowenstein, Daniel" <lowenstein@LAW.UCLA.EDU>:

	Thanks Nate.  A couple of questions and a couple of comments.

	1.  Most importantly, who DID make the comment about the 
Harvard
faculty?  Are we expecting a 5-4 split on that issue?

	2. On the subject of 5-4 splits, why do you not expect one in
Vieth?
>From your message it seems reasonably likely that Stevens, Breyer
and Souter
will support the plaintiffs (or, perhaps, vote against the plaintiffs
but
support a more interventionist position than Bandemer's).  I think
you did
not mention Ginsburg.  But she has been occasionally known to team up
with
Stevens, Breyer and Souter.  O'Connor, Rehnquist and Scalia sound
very
likely to vote for the state and either to preserve Bandemer or close
the
door more tightly.  All we have heard about Thomas is that he was
unhappy to
be there, but he has been known to team with Scalia once or twice. 
So
what's so unlikely about 5-4?

	3. A predominance standard, apparently of interest to Breyer at
least, makes somewhat more sense for partisan gerrymandering than for
racial
gerrymandering.  As I pointed out in a 1998 article (which no doubt
made
Nate wish he had not invited me to the symposium in which it was
published),
the predominance standard is a fiction in the RG cases.  All of them
were
situations in which the state had to create a specified number of
majority-minority districts in order to get Section 5 clearance from
DOJ,
which meant in order to avoid having a plan imposed by a court.  The
racial
quota was not balanced against other redistricting goals, it was the
prerequisite that must be met no matter what.  That is obviously not
true in
the case of a partisan plan.  But all the difficulties with
predominace
identified by other commentators are still present.

	4. I very much agree with Nate that the major reason 
gerrymandering
is more potent now than previously is not technology but a more
partisan
pattern of voter behavior.  I think O'Connor was right that
redistricting is
a self-limiting enterprise.  (As they say, even stopped clocks are
right
twice a day.)  The more reliably voters vote partisanly, the less
constricting those limits are.  Matters of degree are important here.
 I
don't think that even now, voters are so partisanly reliable that
judicial
intervention is nearly justified.  But there is an additional point. 
There
is no reason to assume that the present trend toward more partisan
voting
will go on forever.  To the contrary, as with the stock market, the
only
reliable prediction regarding voter behavior is that it will
fluctuate.
(Admittedly, the stock market fluctuates more rapidly.)  Why should
this
decade's voter trend result in a new judicial intervention into
states'
electoral processes that will have less cognizable purpose and more
elusive
criteria for judgment than any of the Court's previous
interventions?

ΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚ Best, 
ΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚ Daniel Lowenstein 
ΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚ UCLA Law School 
ΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚ 405 Hilgard 
ΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚ Los Angeles, California 90095-1476 
ΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚΚ 310-825-5148 



-----Original Message-----
From: npersily@law.upenn.edu [mailto:npersily@law.upenn.edu] 
Sent: Thursday, December 11, 2003 6:24 AM
To: election-law@majordomo.lls.edu
Cc: Rick Hasen
Subject: from the court... in vieth



Here are a few paraphrased tidbits from the oral argument in Vieth, 
which I attended with my students yesterday.  Some of the comments 
repeat the description in SCOTUSBLOG and in Roy's post, but I figured

I might as well send them along since I had already wrote this up 
(although these are not from notes, so take Roy's post as more 
authoritative). 

In short, it was rough sledding for the Appellants.  By the end of
the 
argument it seemed more likely to me that the Court would reverse 
Bandemer and hold partisan gerrymandering claims nonjusticiable, than

it would strike down the Pennsylvania plan.  The reasons were what we

all predicted:  the lack of any administrable standards to define
when 
such a gerrymander rises to a constitutional violation and the fear 
(ironic though it may be) of venturing farther into the political 
thicket.

The tone for the whole argument was set by Justice O'Connor's first 
comment:  "Maybe the lesson since Bandemer - given that no court has

found an unconstitutional partisan gerrymander - is that we should
get 
out of this mess altogether."  "Hands off", I think she said.

Justice Scalia agreed, asking "isn't it peculiar for us to recognize

the possibility of a constitutional violation but then never find a 
situation which satisfies the standard."  He also later suggested
that 
Article I leaves these disputes in the hands of state legislatures.

The Chief Justice pressed:  There is nothing in our constitutional 
tradition for holding these gerrymanders unconstitutional - nothing
in 
the text or traditions or history.  If you look at people like Canon

and Dirksen - partisanship has always been a part of this process. 
No 
one has believed that partisanship should be removed from the 
process.  Indeed, the word democracy isn't even in the Constitution. 

[Scalia interjected - let alone party]

The lion's share of the argument was dedicated to the appellants 
proposed standard, namely that a constitutional violation occurs when

the party receiving a majority of the votes consistently cannot win 
even close to a majority of the seats.  Not a single Justice appeared

willing to sign on to this standard.  In fact, it was unclear to me 
whether the Justices even understood it.  It reminded me of the famed

(and rejected) Banzhaf index from the one-person, one-vote cases. 
The 
Justices seemed likewise suspicious that judges (or anyone) could 
figure out whether the congressional delegation was consistently 
unreflective of majority will.

>From their responses, it appeared the Justices thought of this as 
either (1) a standard that might always be satisfied or (2) a 
potential morasse in which claims always get thrown into courts, and

we rely on experts to fight it out as to whether the data show a 
continued denial of majority rule.  Paul Smith for the Appellants 
analogized the inquiry to a Section 2 VRA case.

Justice Breyer remarked:  What you are describing here is government

by experts, not government by the people.  [At which point, I wanted

to ask him: "Your point being?"]

Then Breyer said:  This reminds me of what John Kenneth Galbraith
used 
to say: "I'd rather be governed by 50 people chosen at random than by

the faculty of Harvard University."

Justice Scalia interrupted: "It was William F. Buckley, who said
that."

Justices Stevens and Breyer kept trying to suggest alternative 
standards grounded either in Powell's Bandemer concurrence (Stevens)

or in Shaw (Breyer). 

Stevens suggested the state should be forced to provide at least 
one "neutral" (i.e., unrelated to partisanship) reason for an alleged

partisan gerrymander.

Counsel for PA said that there are no "nonpolitical" reasons.

Stevens suggested compactness, contiguity, respect for political 
subdivisions, reelecting incumbents of both parties [a strange
choice, 
I thought - did he not have Issacharoff's insightful Harvard piece on

his nightstand, like the rest of us do?].

Counsel for PA maintained that given known demographic patterns etc.,

such principles have foreseeable partisan effects.  

One other interesting Stevens moment:  he asked whether it would be 
legal for a majority party to pass a law that gave a higher salary to

members of the majority party.  If not, how was this different?

Counsel for PA didn't really respond directly except to mention that

the leaders of the majority party in the PA legislature actually do 
get higher salaries, owing to their additional duties.

Justice Breyer seemed to suggest a three part standard, which
combined 
Shaw, Justice Stevens's proposal and the Appellants'. He suggested 
that plaintiffs should demonstrate:
(1)	that partisanship was the predominant factor in a districting 
plan
(2)	that no neutral justification could be proffered, and
(3)	that majority will was consistently frustrated

Breyer also spoke a bit about Shaw.  He said that he was against the

standard that came out of the "positive gerrymandering" [i.e., Shaw]

cases.  He had always felt that since partisanship could be used to 
draw districts why can't we use race to draw districts to help out 
minorities.  But "since I lost that battle," perhaps we should now 
apply the same standard to partisan gerrymandering claims - i.e.,
that 
partisanship cannot be the predominant factor. 

Counsel for PA reemphasized that partisanship was always part of the

process, and he implied that no one was really injured by a partisan

gerrymander.

One thing that struck me was how the debate in the Court seemed 
completely detached from the mass of empirical work done on partisan

gerrymandering.  This was all the more surprising given the excellent

amicus briefs assembled by the Appellants from Tom Mann et al., and 
from Jacobson and Grofman (whose brief actually supported neither 
party).  [Although, like O'Connor et al, I am particularly worried 
about courts getting deeply involved in these disputes and think that

should decide this case, I think the evidence that partisan 
gerrymanders, or any gerrymander, were more successful in 2002 than 
previously is hard to dispute.  This is due less to a function of the

new technology, which everyone seems to emphasize, than it is to the

stability of partisan preferences in the electorate.  People point to

the rise in the number of independent voters out there (despite Keith

et al., The Myth of the Independent Voter) and assume there is a huge

mass of voters switching sides between elections or as they move down

the ballot.  That is just not true.  Larry Bartels has the best 
article - I think it is in the AJPS from two years ago -- on this.]

It seemed that several Justices (I think Kennedy was one) continue to

believe that partisan gerrymanders are self-regulating - i.e., the 
more greedy the controlling party is, the more likely it is to risk 
losing many seats.  In other words, The Honorable Bruce Cain might
get 
another cite here as he did in Bandemer.  [Given the other news of
the 
day - i.e., McConnell - I guess they have only read his early work.]

Justice Scalia stressed that losing elections may have more to do
with 
the inability of the minority party to persuade people over to its 
side. How do we know they are losing because of the gerrymander? he 
asked.
Concerning administrability, Scalia asked: what would we look at - 
party registration data? Election returns?  If so, which election 
returns and for how many elections?  How do you know in which way
they 
are going to vote in the next election?  What do you do in a state 
like Minnesota where they have a vibrant third party like the Farmer-
Labor?
[Note: the Farmer Labor "Party" is basically merged with the 
Democratic Party.]  

On a similar note, the Counsel for PA argued that the Appellants' 
standard, which would look at past election returns, would inevitably

be biased in favor of a party that was losing voters.  "Some of these

people have switched parties, some have died, etc."  Several Justices

thought this argument was particularly clever.  It also emphasized an

inherent difficulty in these types of cases:  you will never know for

sure that majority will has been consistently frustrated or that one

party has been systematically screwed until a few elections (2 or 3)

have passed.  Then litigation might take a year or so, and before you

know it, it is time to redistrict again.

Justice Souter didn't say much except to suggest that most of the 
predictions of the Republicans in this case came to fruition.  They 
only lost one seat that they thought they were going to win.  "You 
don't have to bat a thousand" to prove a constitutional violation.

For counsel for PA - the fact that one of the expected Republican 
districts ended up going to a Democrat, showed how these gerrymanders

are unpredictable.  [FYI - they were discussing Congressman Jim 
Hoeffel's district.  He was paired in a republican leaning district 
with a republican incumbent, George Gekas, and narrowly won.  He will

now be running against Arlen Specter for Senate and his seat is
likely 
to go Republican.]  Also of note, given the claim that Dems were 
completely shut out of the process:  About 40% of Democrats in the PA

assembly voted in favor of the plan.

Justice Kennedy (the key vote if this is going to be a 5-4 decision,

which I think it won't) didn't say all that much; though toward the 
end he asked:  "Your argument would apply to all elections, even down

to every city council, water district, etc. right?"  Paul Smith 
responded:  "Yes, even local governments can violate constitutional 
rights."

So, in short, it was a bad day for Democrats, those who want the
Court 
to breathe notions of competition into the Constitution, and those of

us who profit off redistricting chaos.  It was a good day for Tom 
Delay, political cartelmeisters, and Frankfurter enthusiasts.

Genially,
Nate



----
Nathaniel Persily
Assistant Professor
University of Pennsylvania Law School
3400 Chestnut Street
Philadelphia, PA 19104
(o) 215-898-0167
(f) 215-573-2025
npersily@law.upenn.edu
http://persily.pennlaw.net/