Tom Round wrote:
Hello from the antipodes,
Whether multi-seat electoral
districts with proportional (STV, party-list) or semi-proportional
(cumulative or limited vote) voting systems are easier or harder to
gerrymander than are single-seaters, depends heavily on two factors:
the minimum number of seats per district, and whether even numbers are
allowed.
There is a huge difference
between, say, Ireland (with 3-, 4- and 5-seat districts) and Tasmania,
Malta and the Australian Capital Territory (which use only 5- and/or
7-seaters). Once every district has at least five seats, and an odd
number (so that a party or coalition with over 50% of the votes in a
district is guaranteed more than half of its seats), the potential
gains from gerrymandering boundaries, in the sense of deliberately
manipulating where the borderlines are placed, dwindles almost to
vanishing point.
By contrast, Ireland in the
1970s saw the refinement of the art of "Tullymandering" (named after
the Minister who drew up the electoral boundaries for the 1974 [?] Dail
Eireann election). The secret here is to put as many 3-seaters as
possible in your own stronghold areas, and as many 4-seaters as you can
in the opposing party's fiefdoms. Suppose that, based on population,
each side's stronghold regions are entitled to 24 seats out of 48. You
divide your own area into eight three-seaters. PR gives you two seats
out of three in every district, making the result there 16-8. But you
divide your opponents' areas into six four-seaters. Under normal
circumstances, each electorate is deadlocked 2-2 in its representation.
So both sides win 12 of 24 seats. Overall, you've won 28 out of 48
seats with as little as 50.1% of the votes in your half of the state
and 40.1% of the votes in your opponents' half.
[I did say "under normal
circumstances" -- the Tullymander backfired because the Minister's
party polled so poorly in the four-seater districts that it dropped
below the 40% threshold needed to hold two seats, and so was
annihilated!]
Once you get over 5 seats, this
becomes harder, especially since larger multi-seat electorates will (on
balance) each contain a larger percentage of the total electorate and
therefore be more evenly balanced. (If your state has 49
single-seaters, there'll very probably be a handful that are 70% safe
for one party; but it's very likely, if the state had seven 7-seaters,
that in a district accounting for 14-15% of the whole state the "red"
and "blue" voters will cancel out more evenly).
Regarding cumulative voting:
Here's a query for those who know more about US voting machines than I
do ... Suppose one wanted to introduce a crude form of
"semi-preferential" Cumulative Vote. The voter could approve as many
candidates as she liked (or up to the number of seats). Her vote is
then divided equally among the candidates she votes for -- the system
used in Peoria, I believe -- instead of dividing your votes 2-2-1, say,
you vote for three candidates and they each get 0.333 of your vote.
Then the lowest candidates are
eliminated one by one. If one of the three candidates you vote for is
eliminated, your vote is re-adjusted so as to give 0.500 to the two
surviving candidates only. This continues until the number of
candidates equals vacancies plus one, or until the required number of
candidates have reached the Droop quota. (Note that with a single seat
this would reduce to simple Approval Voting.) So if your party ran,
say, five candidates for five seats, you could vote for all of them and
the system would reduce the number of surviving candidates to the
maximum number your party's total vote was capable of electing.
What I am curious about is
this: Are existing US voting machines capable of, say, scanning ballots
and saying "43,838 ballots contain votes for Smith, Jones and Brown...
31,622 ballots contain votes for Smith, Jones and Weinberger ..." -- or
is that too complicated?
Cheers all
Tom
--------------------------------------------------------------------------
Dr Tom Round
BA (Hons), LLB (UQ), PhD (Griff)
Research Fellow, Key Centre for Ethics,
Law, Justice and Governance (KCELJAG)
Room 1.10, Macrossan Building, Nathan Campus
Griffith University, Queensland [Australia] 4111
Ph: (061 or 07) 3875 3817
Mobile: 0438 167 304
Fax: (061 or 07) 3875 6634
E-mail: T.Round@gu.edu.au
Web: http://www.gu.edu.au/centre/KCELJAG/
--------------------------------------------------------------------------
Guy-Uriel Charles
<gcharles@umn.edu> Sent by:
owner-election-law_gl@majordomo.lls.edu
12-02-2004 06:58
To: Mark Rush
<RushM@wlu.edu> cc: election-law@majordomo.lls.edu Subject: Re:
Charles and single-member districts
A few responses to Mark Rush's
points:
First, while all electoral
structures are manipulable single-member districting presents greater
opportunities for manipulation and are manipulable in ways that are not
as transparent than say at large electoral systems. This point is
supported by scholarship by Rae, Riker, Amy, and Colomer. In fact, Rush
himself has stated: "Gerrymandering is a natural product of the
single-member plurality system (SMP) of representation built upon
geographically determined constituencies that uses the
first-past-the-post method of counting votes." Gerrymandering [in the
US]: out of the political thicket and into the quagmire. 682-685 in PS
27 (4), Dec. 94.
The point of my piece, as Paul
Johnston noted, was that multi-member districting in combination with
some other device (I used cumulative voting, but only as illustrative)
reduces the opportunity for gerrymandering in a manner that should be
constitutionally significant.
Second, Mark Rush's second
point is unclear. The fact that campaign finance laws may favour
incumbents is not an argument in favour of other incumbent-preferring
devices. Indeed, many scholars have argued (with some receptivity from
the Courts) that courts ought to strike down electoral rules that can
be justified solely as incumbent protection devices.
As an aside, though I'm a bit
over half-way through Larios v. Cox, I'm struck by the manner in which
that court is reacting to what it perceives to be a partisan
gerrymander and to a lesser extent an incumbent-protection plan. It is
also interesting that the Court uses the equi-population principle to
object to what it understands to be a partisan and incumbent protecting
gerrymander.
Let me also add that there is a
debate within the political science literature on whether and how
campaign finance laws advantage incumbents.
Third, Mark Rush, fundamentally
misunderstands my associational argument. Voters form all sorts of
blocs, partisan, ideological, racial, etc. The question is whether the
state can determine which blocs are salient and which ones are not. On
Mark Rush's specific points. I'll leave it up to him to decide whether
Larry Bartels is a student of American politics, but his 2000 APSR
article characterises Mark Rush's claims as "exaggerated and outdated."
See also Marc Hetherington's 2001 APSR piece.
The FindLaw piece is a preview
of a longer law review article. I'll post to SSRN when it is finished.
Responses to criticisms of my proposal will have to await the longer
piece. The associational argument is developed in 91 California Law
Review 1209 (2003) for those interested.
guy
Mark Rush wrote: This sort of
argument against SMDs is a bit too simplistic.
First, multi-member districts
can be used to gerrymander just as easily as SMDs. The list had a
discussion about this earlier. Dick Katz, I believe cited Doug Rae's
work on this.
Second, the complaint about
incumbent entrenchment is a red herring. Campaign finance laws do as
much if not more to advantage incumbents than any redistricting.
Finally, the associational
rights argument is weak. It works only if we can assume that voters
really do form partisan blocs. Any student of American politics knows
that this simply is not true. American split tickets, have notoriously
weak partisan identification and, as I noted in a book and two
articles, when they are redistricted, they tend to change their voting
patterns. (This makes perfect sense: change the choices, change their
behaviour).
Mark E. Rush Professor of
Politics Washington and Lee University Lexington, VA 24450
http://home.wlu.edu/~rushm
(540) 458-8904
(540) 458-8639 (fax)
--
Guy-Uriel E. Charles Associate
Professor of Law University of Minnesota Law School
229-19th Avenue South
Minneapolis, MN
612.626.9154 (voice)
612.625-2011 (fax)
gcharles@umn.edu
Faculty Affiliate The Center
for the Study of Political Psychology University of Minnesota