Rick's fascinating brief (written
with Sam Issacharoff and Burt Neuborne) raises a fundamental, or
baseline question that has perplexed me since my work on Cook v.
Gralike. It's a question, I suppose, that only someone who's an
election-law novice (such as yours truly) might ask -- namely,
what gives states any authority to apply outcome-specific
considerations in drawing districts? The state's power to redistrict
derives, doesn't it, from the Elections Clause -- which in theory gives
the state only a procedural, or house-keeping function. Why isn't a
state acting extra-constitutionally whenever it uses
considerations such as partisanship, incumbency protection, or party
"balance" in its consideration of how to draw districts? Why isn't
that just as much of a violation of the Elections Clause as when the
state structures the ballot itself with such considerations in mind
(e.g., preferred ballot ordering, or "scarlet letter" labeling)?
I recognize that this theory would
invalidate virtually all redistricting that's been undertaken over the
past few decades (if not longer). (Rick's brief only argues for a rule
against mid-decade redistricting, but I'm not sure why its logic
wouldn't in effect require that all redistricting be performed
by courts, computers or "experts," rather than partisan state
legislatures.) So no doubt it's too extreme to be taken seriously.
But on what basis? Has the Court ever explained what gives states the
authority to gerrymander?
I realize, by the way, that this is
similar to my question of a couple of months ago about why all state
partisan gerrymandering doesn't violate the First Amendment. Perhaps
the similarity makes some sense, because as Cook and Rick's
brief demonstrate, the First Amendment and Elections Clause
considerations are in some respect conterminous or analogous here.
Is there any justification
here other than "It's been occurring since the dawn of time"?
----- Original Message -----
Sent: Tuesday, January 10, 2006 4:00
PM
Subject: message from Rick Pildes
> Rick Pildes writes:
>
>
> We did not cite any unpublished academic work, including the
> forthcoming article you mention. As you must know, that
particular
> article has been powerfully and, I believe, devastatingly
criticized by
> another forthcoming article by Michael McDonald * in the very same
issue
> of that forthcoming journal. As McDonald points out, the article
you
> mention bizarrely used the 1988 Presidential election results to
assess
> the competitiveness of the 1990 congressional districts and then
to
> compare the competitiveness of the post-redistricting 1992
districts,
> the article used the 1992 Presidential election results * even
though
> that was a three-way contest in which Ross Perot received 18.9% of
the
> vote. As McDonald's article shows, that unhelpful baseline from
the
> unusual 1992 election completely distorts all of the results in
the
> paper you note. When McDonald revisits the data using "more valid
> measures of district competitiveness," as he puts it, he finds no
> question that "redistricting is shown to reduce the number of
> competitive congressional districts, contrary to Abramowitz et.
al."
>
> We would like to have cited this unpublished work, but I do not
invite
> the Court to rely on unpublished work, nor do I want to cite it
before
> publication. No matter how late in the production process an
article
> is, things can still change before publication. Indeed, I would
like
> also to have cited additional unpublished work, including
additional
> work by McDonald, that further confirms the obvious link between
safe
> districts and non-competitiveness. As McDonald concludes in
"Drawing
> the Line on District Competition," after data analysis: "Those
engaged
> in redistricting seem to have perfected their game, resulting in
fewer
> competitive districts in the 1991 and 2001 redistricting
cycles." But
> I also did not cite this work because it too was not in
publication when
> production of the brief was completed. The unpublished paper in
your
> email is, as far as I am aware, considered quite an outlier among
the
> studies that have looked at the 2000 elections. In advance of
> publication, it has already been convincingly shown to be mistaken.
>
> Please note that our brief never says that safe districting is the
only
> cause of the absence of competitive elections. We note that it is
a
> contributing cause. I believe the social-science evidence
> overwhelmingly confirms this, even including unpublished work,
> especially for the 2000s, which is the focus of the case.
>
> Rick Pildes
>
> Richard Pildes
> Sudler Family Professor of Constitutional Law
> Co-Director, NYU Center on Law and Security
> NYU School of Law
> 40 Washington Sq. So. NYC, NY 10012
> phone: 212 998-6377
> fax: 212 995-3662
>
>>>> Rick Hasen <Rick.Hasen@lls.edu> 1/10/2006 2:50 PM >>>
> From: "Kimball, David C." <kimballd@msx.umsl.edu>
> To: <election-law_gl@majordomo.lls.edu>
> X-OriginalArrivalTime: 10 Jan 2006 19:11:19.0687 (UTC)
> FILETIME=[A354B970:01C61619]
>
>
>
> The post about the Texas brief on political competition reminded
me to
> add something. There are a number of studies which find that
> redistricting is not to blame for the decline in competitive
contests or
> for the incumbency advantage in American congressional elections,
> including this article from the January 2006 issue of Journal of
> Politics by Alan Abramowitz and his colleagues
> (http://journalofpolitics.org/files/68_1/Incumbency.pdf). Not everyone
> agrees with this finding, but I didn't see any of the studies which
> claim to exonerate redistricting cited in the Pildes, Issacharoff,
and
> Neuborne brief.
>
> - David Kimball
>
> =20
>
> David C. Kimball
>
> Associate Professor, Department of Political Science
>
> University of Missouri-St. Louis
>
> One University Blvd., 347 SSB
>
> St. Louis, MO 63121-4400
>
> phone: 314-516-6050
>
> web page: http://www.umsl.edu/~kimballd
>
> =20
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>