Subject: Re: [EL] Redistricting answer |
From: Douglas Johnson |
Date: 10/30/2010, 9:10 PM |
To: "antoine.yoshinaka@ucr.edu" <antoine.yoshinaka@ucr.edu>, 'Michael McDonald' <mmcdon@gmu.edu>, 'Election Law' <election-law@mailman.lls.edu> |
"when many "old"
Republican constituents are replaced with "new" Republican
constituents."
Parties
in control do this to their own elected officials too: this is how California Democrats
beat Representative Gary Condit in the 2002 primary, instead of risking his
losing the November general election.
I
suspect we may see the same thing in Ohio in 2011: Republicans may put
"new" Republicans in Jean Schmidt's district to enable a 'chosen'
challenger to beat her in the primary (she's had a series of very close
re-election campaigns, despite having a safe Republican seat -- essentially a
negative incumbency effect).
Bruce
Cain's "The Reapportionment Puzzle" (1984) describes an extremely
similar scenario in detail, though it's slightly different in that Cain focused
on how removing incumbents' home residences can make districts more competitive
without making any demographic changes to the districts (or at least trigger
problems among the 'out' party's elected officials).
-
Doug
Douglas
Johnson
Fellow
Rose
Institute of State and Local Government
Claremont
McKenna College
o
909-621-8159
m
310-200-2058
douglas.johnson@cmc.edu
www.RoseReport.org
-----Original
Message-----
From: election-law-bounces@mailman.lls.edu
[mailto:election-law-bounces@mailman.lls.edu] On Behalf Of Antoine Yoshinaka
Sent: Saturday, October 30, 2010 10:52 AM
To: Michael McDonald; 'Election Law'
Subject: Re: [EL] Redistricting answer
One
reason why there is an upward limit to competition may be due to partisan
segregation. Bruce Oppenheimer has some work showing that more and more
Republicans live near Republicans and Democrats near Democrats. So it may
be difficult to draw districts with a good number of both R and D voters.
As
for the finding that optimal partisan gerrymandering leads to safe districts, I
would like to add one wrinkle. Chad Murphy and I published a couple of
articles (2009 Political Geography and forthcoming Political Research
Quarterly) in which we show that partisan mapmakers are able to target
out-party districts in a different way, by inducing population
instability. So for instance, it may be the case that an out-party
Republican incumbent's district is composed mainly of Republican constituents
both prior to and following redistricting (i.e., it's a safe district in terms
of partisanship). However, when many "old" Republican
constituents are replaced with "new" Republican constituents, it
creates an environment propitious to a competitive election. That's what
we found happened in 2002. By looking mainly at partisanship, optimal
gerrymandering models potentially miss an important source of heterogeneity
which leads to competition.
Antoine
--------------------
Antoine
Yoshinaka
Assistant
Professor
Dept.
of Political Science
2217
Watkins Hall
University
of California, Riverside
Riverside,
CA 92521
Tel:(951)827-4688
Fax:(951)827-3933
Email:
antoine.yoshinaka@ucr.edu
Website:
http://politicalscience.ucr.edu/people/faculty/yoshinaka/index.html
----
Original message ----
>Date:
Fri, 29 Oct 2010 22:00:53 -0400
>From:
election-law-bounces@mailman.lls.edu (on behalf of Michael McDonald
<mmcdon@gmu.edu>)
>Subject:
Re: [EL] Redistricting answer
>To:
"'Election Law'" <election-law@mailman.lls.edu>
>
>Owen
and Grofman (Political Geography 1988) create a formal mode and find
>that
partisan and incumbent protection gerrymanders are the same in terms of
>competition.
I illustrate this simply in my redistricting chapter for the
>Marketplace
of Democracy edited volume (edited with John Samples). My
>dissertation
took this one step further and formally showed that to maximize
>expected
number seats or maximize probability of majority control in the
>presence
of greater volatility (i.e., partisan gerrymandering), the optimal
>response
is to draw safer districts. I published elements of this in:
>Michael
P. McDonald. 2008. "Redistricting and the Decline of Competitive
>Congressional
Districts." in Mobilizing Democracy: A Comparative Perspective
>on
Institutional Barriers and Political Obstacles.
>
>I
would not disagree on the second part about the upward limit. Read my
>Midwest
Mapping Project report, which you can download at
>http://elections.gmu.edu/Redistricting.html,
which generally shows something
>similar.
To see what might happen if one were to directly incorporate
>competition
into the redistricting criteria and balance it against other
>goals,
including the Voting Rights Act -- and not demote it below the other
>criteria
as Arizona did -- I recommend reading the results of the 2009 Ohio
>Secretary
of State redistricting competition at
>http://www.sos.state.oh.us/SOS/redistricting.aspx.
This competition shows
>that
reformers' and the voting rights community's goals are not as at odds
>with
one another as one may think, that is it is possible to simultaneously
>draw
a Cleveland voting rights district and to draw districts that are more
>fair
and competitive than the current Ohio congressional redistricting plan.
>This
competition illustrates why I favor broad public participation in
>redistricting,
so that we may have a better sense of the trade-offs between
>various
goals and have an informed debate about those goals and the types of
>districts
that may result.
>
>============
>Dr.
Michael P. McDonald
>Associate
Professor, George Mason University
>Non-Resident
Senior Fellow, Brookings Institution
>
>
Mailing address:
>(o)
703-993-4191
George
Mason University
>(f)
703-993-1399
Dept. of Public and International Affairs
>mmcdon@gmu.edu
4400 University Drive - 3F4
>http://elections.gmu.edu
Fairfax, VA 22030-4444
>
>
>-----Original
Message-----
>From:
election-law-bounces@mailman.lls.edu
>[mailto:election-law-bounces@mailman.lls.edu]
On Behalf Of nate@persily.com
>Sent:
Friday, October 29, 2010 8:05 PM
>To:
Douglas Johnson; Election Law
>Subject:
Re: [EL] Redistricting answer
>
>Since
2002, about 18 percent of congressional seats have changed hands (that
>is,
a D and an R have held the seat). Jason Kelly and I have a paper on this
>that
we will post once we incorporate the 2010 election results. As far as
>I
can tell, the seats that changed hands were proportionally distributed
>among
partisan and bipartisan gerrymanders. For every successful bipartisan
>gerrymander
(e.g., California) there were others that were less successful
>(e.g.
New York). Same is true for partisan gerrymanders (compare Florida
>with
Pennsylvania).
>
>I
guess one could say that gerrymanders become more unstable over the course
>of
a decade, all else equal. But each decade seems to differ from the last.
>Compare
the 2002 and 2004 elections with 1982 and 1994, for example.
>
>I
would say (perhaps inviting controversy) that absent intentional efforts
>to
draw competitive districts, it might be difficult to draw more than about
>a
third of House districts that would be likely to change hands throughout
>the
decade. However, a lot could happen in terms of shifting party ID over
>the
next ten years.
>
>Sent
from my Verizon Wireless BlackBerry
>