"Lobbying, Rent Seeking, and the Constitution"
I have just posted this
draft on SSRN. Here is the abstract:
Politicians across the political spectrum, from Barack Obama to
Sarah Palin and Rand Paul, routinely castigate lobbyists for
engaging in supposedly corrupt activities or having unequal
access to elected officials. Since attaining office President
Obama has imposed unprecedented new lobbying regulations, and he
is not alone: both Congress and state and local legislative
bodies have done so in recent years. At the same time, federal
courts, relying upon the Supreme Court's new campaign finance
decision in Citizens United v. FEC, have begun striking down
lobbying regulations, including important regulations limiting
campaign finance activities of lobbyists and imposing a waiting
period before legislators or legislative staffers may work as
lobbyists. Two courts have held such laws could not be sustained
on anticorruption grounds, and they are unlikely to be sustained
on political equality grounds either.
This Article advances an alternative rationale which could
support some, though not all, of the recent wave of new lobbying
regulations: the state's interest in preventing the socially
inefficient activity of rent-seeking. Less technically, the
government's interest is in promoting national economic welfare.
Rent-seeking occurs when resources are dedicated to capturing a
government benefit, rather than being put to a productive use,
and lobbyists are often the key actors securing such benefits.
The rent-seeking analysis focuses attention on the systemic
societal costs of lobbying, rather than engaging in unjustified
vilification of the vast majority of lobbyists.
Part I of this Article provides an overview of the current state
of lobbying regulation and lobbying jurisprudence. Part II
proposes a new anti-rent-seeking rationale for lobbying
regulation. It begins by describing the political science
literature on how lobbying works, as well as current statistics
on the extent of lobbying on the federal level and the costs of
lobbyist-driven rent-seeking on the national economy. Some of
the new and proposed lobbying regulations, such as anti-bundling
provisions and anti-revolving door provisions, could decrease
the total amount of interest group rent-seeking. The state's
anti-rent-seeking interest must be balanced against the First
Amendment costs of lobbying regulation in infringing on the
right to speak and petition the government. I defend the
reduction of rent-seeking as an important (even potentially
compelling) state interest that justifies at least some new
lobbying regulations against constitutional challenge.
Part III turns to objections and extensions of the argument. I
respond to objections on both ends and means. On ends, I
consider the circumstances in which the promotion of national
economic efficiency can trump First Amendment rights. On means,
I consider whether there is sufficient proof that lobbying
regulations are sufficiently tailored to a reduction in
rent-seeking and whether, because the "hydraulic" nature of
money in politics, attempts to regulate lobbying so as to
decrease rent-seeking will be easy to evade. Under extensions, I
consider whether the anti-rent seeking rationale could be used
to justify the reenactment, as suggested by Justice Stevens, of
the ban on the spending of corporate treasury funds in candidate
elections, as well as the recent SEC "pay-to-play" rule for
investment advisers.
This is an early draft that I'll be presenting at workshops over
the next few months. Comments welcome!
Posted by Rick Hasen at
08:31
AM
"Campaign finance reformers carry on without
their leader"
The LA Times offers this
report, which discusses the prospects of a disclosure law
in the new Congress (I would not hold my breath).
Posted by Rick Hasen at
08:24
AM
"Misidentified Priorities: Newly elected
Republicans are pushing state-level voter-ID laws designed to
disenfranchise minority voters."
Tova Wang has written this
piece for The American Prospect.
Posted by Rick Hasen at
08:17
AM
Welcome to the Blogosphere....
to the Corporate
Political Activity Law blog.
Posted by Rick Hasen at
08:08
AM
Signing Statements, Again
Charlie Savage has an interesting NYT
piece discussing signing statements in relation to
Guantanamo.
Posted by Rick Hasen at
08:05
AM
"Democrats Plan Push to Curtail Use of
Filibusters"
The NY Times offers this
report.
Posted by Rick Hasen at
08:02
AM
"Is The Supreme Court a Majoritarian
Institution"
Rick Pildes has posted this
draft on SSRN (forthcoming Supreme Court Review).
Here is the abstract:
In recent years, a number of scholars have argued that the
Supreme Court has always been, and is destined to be, a
"majoritarian" institution. Building on the work of Robert Dahl,
these scholars collectively offer both historical and predictive
claims: they assert that the Court's decisions have tended to
reflect the values and preferences of national majorities and
that deep structural forces and incentives constrain will
continue to constrain the Court from departing from the
preferences of these national majorities.
This article takes issue with those claims. Using as a starting
point the Court's dramatically countermajoritarian recent
decision in the Citizens United case, this article identifies at
least six problems with the majoritarian thesis: (1) lack of
clarity about who the relevant majority is that purportedly
constrains the Court, such as national lawmaking majorities,
national popular opinion majorities, or other possible
definitions of "the majority"; (2) lack of convincing accounts
of the mechanisms by which one or another of these majorities
manages to constrain the Court; (3) disagreement about whether
the Court's most momentous decisions, such as Brown v. Board of
Education, were in fact majoritarian or not; (4) confusion
between whether individual Court decisions reflect majoritarian
preferences and whether the Court over long periods of time
eventually reflects majoritarian beliefs; (5) failure to take
into adequate account the changing power of the Court over time;
(6) issues about whether data support the majoritarian thesis.
In addition, this article argues that good reasons exist to
believe that the history of judicial review will not necessarily
predict its future. However independent the Court might or might
not have been in the past of political and popular constraints,
the Court is likely to have more autonomy going forward than in
the past. The strongest mechanism through which the Court
reflects the outcomes of electoral processes, the appointments
process, has been attenuated by the much longer average time
Justices now serve; seats now become vacant on average every 3.1
years, rather than the 1.6 years that had long been the norm.
That makes even more random any linkage between judicial
appointments and national electoral outcomes.
The article concludes by offering Citizens United as a powerful
reminder that, despite the best efforts of modern majoritarian
theorists, Bickel's countermajoritarian difficulty endures.
Citizens United may prove to be an isolated but important
episode -- or a harbinger of an assertive new era of judicial
review that operates with a good deal of independence from
national lawmaking and popular majorities.
I very much look forward to reading this!
Posted by Rick Hasen at
07:54
AM
"Secretaries of State Up the Political Ante"
Stateline.org offers this
report.
Posted by Rick Hasen at
09:18
PM